New Pricing Policy: Research

TL;DR

A study was conducted to identify opportunities to change the ENS pricing policy. Based on the dynamics of gas and the secondary market, the risks of losing registrations in the event of a price increase were calculated. For each of the domain categories, it is proposed to introduce a price that will both satisfy users and allow ENS to receive additional funds for development. The price should be curved and decrease with each year added to the registration, which will also increase the average selected registration duration.

  • For 3L domains: $640 for the first year, $430 for the second year, $360 for the third, and so on according to the formula P(t) = 420/t + 220.
  • For 4L domains: $160 for the first year, $107.5 for the second year, $80 for the third, and so on according to the formula P(t) = 105/t + 55.
  • For 5L+ domains: $15 for the first year, $10 for the second year, $8.33 for the third, and so on according to the formula P(t) = 10/t + 5.

Motivation

Domain prices were set 8 years ago and have not changed since then. During this time, the US dollar has inflated by 30%, and the industry has grown tenfold.

Recently, funding for Labs and SPP has been expanded. There are also governance token distribution programs, regular grants are issued, and new organizations are emerging that are ready to contribute to the development of ENS.

Therefore, it seems necessary to increase ENS revenue from registrations in order to maintain the ability to continuously improve the product. At the same time, it is extremely important to keep the price within the limits that would satisfy users, so as not to jeopardize scalability and the social purpose.

Under the guidance of Labs and MG Stewards, I analyzed risks and developed pricing strategies aimed at increasing domain revenue and average registration duration without significantly reducing the number of registrations.


Overview

5L+ Price

Flat Model

The base price of domains has never changed, but the gas varies for each transaction. Based on its dynamics and the subsequent reaction of users, we can estimate the risks of losing registrations when the base price increases.

The study found that the gas value does indeed have a negative effect on the number of registrations. The dependence has a power-law form – that is, each new dollar added to the price will have less and less impact on registrations (for example, a step from $5 to $6 will have a much stronger impact than a step from $10 to $11).

This form of dependence opens up opportunities for us to set a flat price even at $20/domain and incur only about 17% of losses. However, it is certainly worth considering the social side of the issue. An extremely important task when changing the price will be not to hit vulnerable categories of users. Therefore, the sample was divided in different ways in order to find some category of users that would react to the gas in a special way.

The most eloquent and important division in the context of the issue was the division into users registering their 1-3 domains and users registering 4 or more domains.

  • Those registering 1-3 domains (or regular users) are newbies or just ordinary users who most likely have no commercial interest in registrations. They are important for the scalability of ENS, since there are a lot of them and they have a large potential for word of mouth. It turned out that they are much more susceptible to the influence of gas and they can safely be called a more vulnerable category to price increases. At the above-mentioned price of $20/domain, we will lose up to 30% of their number, which can be detrimental to the future of ENS.
  • Those registering 4 or more domains (or heavy users) are speculators or just a very active group. They are certainly also important for ENS, but they almost do not react to the offered gas. Even with a price increase to $20, we will lose only a couple of percent of them.

The difference in their behavior is clearly visible in this graph:

As the gas decreases, the share of regular users in registrations increases and vice versa. Therefore, when choosing the final price, we need to focus on the change in regular users. You can see a table of possible flat prices here. However, a flat price is not recommended and here is why:

Curve Model

The fact is that users have been found to have pronounced rational behavior. They register domains for a longer period, the higher the gas. You can clearly see this in this infographic:

Up until the $40 gas price, there is a clear pattern. Users tend to average out the price per domain/year until they reach a certain sweet spot. For example, you are offered $10 gas. You would then choose 2 years of registration to make the price per domain/year $10 instead of $15 if you chose 1 year of registration.

We are currently seeing very low gas, and ENS will be releasing NameChain in the future. If we have a flat base price and negligible gas, users will lose financial incentive to register domains for more than 1 year (they currently register them for about 2 years on average).

Users are not aiming for a specific average figure (for example, $10/year), but for a point where the graph will have a certain curvature. To be precise, they stop their choice at the point of the average price with a curvature of 0.04-0.14 (with a median of 0.06). With this insight, along with other known user behavior patterns, we can model a discounted pricing curve for each subsequent year – simulating gas fees as an added cost.

4,300 different price curve options were built that would both satisfy users and bring ENS additional funds for development (you can see all the curves in this table). Extrapolating the curvature rule, which we can do with some reservations*, we can assume that users will choose a registration duration such that the curvature of the average price function is in the range of 0.04-0.14.

It is recommended to introduce a price curve that would set the price for the first year at $15, for the second $10, for the third $8.33, and so on according to the formula P(t) = 10/t + 5. Projectedly, this will give users such a financial incentive to register longer that it will increase the average duration to 5-8 years*.

With such a duration, the average price per year of a domain will be $8-9, which will give ENS an additional 70% of income from 5L+ domains with a loss of 5-10% of regular users. This will also give ENS a lot of money here and now, due to the increased duration of registration.

*The estimated duration of registration is just an extrapolation. Users may not perceive the newly added price exactly the same way they perceive gas, so it is worth treating the estimates as approximate.

3L and 4L Price

There was an attempt to calculate the loss of short name registrations using the same algorithm as with 5L+. However, it turned out that registrants of these domain categories are absolutely not affected by gas. Even if it is $100, it does not reduce the volume.

These domain categories are now more of a point of speculative interest, so it is important to look at the secondary market. It turned out that the volume of registrations correlates with the volume of secondary sales. However, the causation is not so obvious – now we can rather say that these factors are interdependent. Therefore, it is important to prevent the death of the secondary market – not to satisfy speculators, but to prevent the loss of primary registrations.

Analysis of the secondary market revealed its deplorable state. Almost in all categories of 3/4L domains, 60% of sellers are at a loss relative to the funds spent on maintaining the domain, platform and network commission. The only ā€œaliveā€ category turned out to be 1k club, however, the dynamics of their prices, as well as the average time-to-sale, indicate that soon the owners of this category of domains will be at a loss, which will lead to a complete collapse of volumes:

So it is proposed not to increase the average price that they must pay, but for them it is possible to introduce a pricing curve with a starting point at the level of the current base price ($640 and $160, respectively). We can say that by introducing such a system, we make a discount on these domain categories, but at the same time encourage registering them for a longer period. Here are the curves, roughly similar to the one developed for 5L+:

  • For 3L domains: $640 for the first year, $430 for the second year, $360 for the third, and so on according to the formula P(t) = 420/t + 220.
  • For 4L domains: $160 for the first year, $107.5 for the second year, $80 for the third, and so on according to the formula P(t) = 105/t + 55.

Due to the aforementioned lack of impact of gas on these registration categories, we cannot model the changes in registrations when such a price curve is introduced.

Timing

Choosing the optimal timing for introducing a new pricing format is a very important aspect. Take a look at this graph of the 180-day moving regression coefficient for gas:

The higher the graph is now, the more users are willing to pay. Introducing changes when the indicator is at the bottom can lead to a cascading and long-term collapse of registrations. However, introducing changes at the top points is also not worth it – at these times, user behavior is simply so unpredictable that any modeling can only be done within the framework of large assumptions.

The ideal time for new prices is when the 180-day coefficient is within the confidence intervals of the global coefficient. We are in this situation now, and presumably will be in it for the foreseeable future.


Additional Considerations

5L/6L+ Separation

The supply volume of 5-character domains is generally not much higher than 3- and 4-character domains, and this is especially true for meaningful words. Therefore, it would be logical to assume that the price optimum for 5L domains is higher than, for example, for domains 6 or more characters long. Then the 5L+ category could be price-separated into 5L and 6L+.

However, after splitting the sample and using the same gas-based algorithm, it turned out that users do not show any behavior that would suggest that they are willing to pay more for 5L than for 6L+. Sometimes it even works the other way around, and 6L+ domains are valued higher.

That is, there is currently no objective reason to use such price separation. It is safe to say that at some point the market will react to the limited supply of 5L and we will see a willingness to pay a higher price. It is proposed to reconsider this issue in a few years.

Increasing the minimum registration term

Currently, it is possible to register domains for a period shorter than a year (from 28 days). This is most actively used by those registering 3/4L domains and speculators.

We would certainly like to see more long-term registrations, so the possibility of cutting this feature was considered. However, presumably this will not motivate users to register domains for a longer period, but will simply reduce the number of registrations.

The proposed price curve will be a softer force that will solve the problem of a large number of very short-term registrations, so the minimum possible registration period is proposed to remain unchanged.


Methods and Reliability

While the main hypotheses were tested using regularized regression models within a 180-day time window, the findings were also rigorously cross-validated:

  • with other models, including tree and vector machine learning models. For a more accurate risk calculation, over 30,000 non-overfitted models were built, the best of which were selected using Grid Search;
  • within time windows of other sizes and other historical periods. All hypotheses were confirmed to be either homogeneous over time or did not differ much;
  • with classic statistical tests. All variables were also examined using univariate analyses (autoregression, distribution analyses) to eliminate any questionable interpretation.

This post is just a very brief summary of the research. The full study is provided to ENS Labs and MG stewards. If anyone is interested in reviewing the full documentation, it can be provided.

4 Likes

Thanks for doing this @danch.quixote

The first thing that comes to mind is as to whether the DAO is meant to be self sustaining OR profit maximizing. The constitution states in relation to registration fees:

A secondary purpose is to provide enough revenue to the DAO to fund ongoing development and improvement of ENS.

This is my context for my further commentary.


This should be public IMO. Delegates can’t make informed decisions if they can’t see the full study.


My first thought reading this is that it is premised around increasing revenue with pricing structure. The obvious other approach to increasing revenue is with utility such that people want to register more ENS names.

If changes to five letter prices (for example) incentivize longer registrations, that is great for speculation and great for short term revenues, but doesn’t actually get names into the hands of people that will use them. Usage is what will grow ENS, bring more users in, and sustain protocol development moving forward.

3L/4L names I think are the low hanging fruit for increasing revenues. I don’t have the numbers to hand but i think a large portion of three letter names are still available because the prices are prohibitively expensive. The pricing structures were intended to stop excessive speculation, but for the digits at least that hasn’t worked. For 3 letter names it has put off speculation but has had the side effect of putting off real users as well - they have simply chosen longer names, or not register a name at all. Efficient economic allocation is a tough problem.

I’m intrigued to see the full research as I’m curious if a qualitative ā€˜ask the users’ approach has been considered in relation to the problem I.E. asking the question ā€˜What price would a 3L registration need to be for you to register it?’. If we discern that that at a $50 price point all 3L names would be registered, that is an approximate $1M increase in yearly revenue without having complex multi-year pricing structures.

My perception is that the research focuses on an analysis of current registration/renewal patterns but completely new pricing structures might fundamentally change those dynamics.


Other thoughts

  • A unified renewal price ($10?) with well marketed descending price auction for allocation of unregistered 3/4L names?

  • Further research? Connect with DNS Registry operators to see how ā€˜premium registration/renewal’ fees have worked out in practice?

TL;DR

In my opinion, a simple pricing structure that is reasonable ($50 per year for 3L names, $10 per year for all others?), and a product thats good enough that people want to register names (for multiple years) = more registrations = more revenue?

1 Like

ENS has become substantially more useful, and the US dollar has declined substantially in purchasing power since ENS was launched. Both of these point towards a higher price being warranted, and in this instance a higher price serves both the primary goal of regulating registrations and the secondary goal of generating income for the DAO.

Incentivizing longer registrations has the opposite effect - it incentivizes registrations by end users over speculators, because there’s little to no correlation between registration duration and sale price. Speculators are overwhelmingly likely to register for short periods in order to minimize their costs, so they do not benefit from tiered discounts on longer registrations.

4 Likes

I believe ENS DAO uses an accrue accounting method, not cash accounting…So additional funds for development for registration years beyond the current year may-or-may not give ENS a lot of money in the ā€œhere and nowā€, (due to this proposed increased duration of registration), until the later years that they are accrued.

It would certainly be great to increase name registrations, thereby increasing revenue. To this end, the DAO is currently increasing funding for organizations that contribute to improving the product (Labs, Providers, working group grant recipients).

In 2024, the DAO’s expenses almost doubled (from 9m to 16m). However, the number of registrations per year decreased by 100 thousand. In 2025, if the dynamics continue, we will see about 300 thousand registrations, which will be 200 thousand less than in 2024.

This doesn’t mean the strategy of better product → more registrations → higher revenue doesn’t work – it likely does, but on a longer time horizon. Introducing the price curve helps ENS reach that future without needing to curtail today’s broad funding programs .


It’s not entirely clear what ā€œusing themā€ means. If they registered the name for a long term and don’t sell it, that means they are using it.

Nick is absolutely right: the longer the registration period, the more likely the user is the final holder. This pattern holds across all name lengths, on any day of the year, and at any gas price. Speculators consistently choose shorter registration durations than regular users.

For example:

  • Over the last 3 years, regular users registered 5+ letter names for ~900 days on average, while speculators registered them for ~600 days.
  • For 4L names: 480 days vs. 180 days.
  • For 3L names: 340 days vs. 110 days.

This would certainly be useful, but realistically it’s hard to design a user survey that protects privacy, reaches a meaningful sample, and yields actionable insights.

In many ways, gas spending is a useful proxy for user intent and willingness to pay. The amount of gas a user is willing to spent when registring the name reflects both their motivation and price elasticity.


The average duration of 5L+ registrations is about 2 years. If Ethereum had a negligible fee, the average duration of registration would be about 1.2 years, because users would have no financial incentive to register for a longer period. This is exactly what is happening now – gas has fallen to historically low values, and with it the selected duration.

One of the goals of the NameChain development is to eliminate gas from the equation. If ENS maintains a flat price at the time of the release of this network, the income dynamics will collapse, because users will choose short-term registrations.

One might think that ā€œlet them register for a year, they will then extend it.ā€ However, it is far from certain that they will extend it (Currently, more names are being released than registered, https://dune.com/ethereumnameservice/ens-daily). The number of active users/active domains is the main metric that drives scalability, so the incentive for longer registration durations is perhaps one of the main benefits of the proposed pricing curve.

1 Like

Here’s data from our side quest scraping multilingual dictionary for length check.

Language Used Dictionary Size Avg Length Common Length 20% ≤ Length 50% ≤ Length
English 466,434 9.42 9 7 9
Arabic 5,691,498 7.97 8 7 8
Hindi 476,641 7.15 6 5 7
Korean 366,503 3.56 3 2 3
Chinese 406,588 3.35 3 2 3

~50% of Korean and Chinese dictionary words are less than 3 utf-8 chars.
~20% of Korean and Chinese dictionary words are less than 2 utf-8 chars.

it’d be really nice to give huge discount for non-english ENS domains.

cc @raffy :pray:

1 Like

Is this a joke, so you are going to reward 3L, 4L holders by discounting their registration over time, while increasing 5L+ by 3 fold for the first year and 50% in the second year.

1 Like

Why not change the by-laws of the DAO, and use the ENS token inside the layer 2 Namechain you are creating as a utility token, Offer a pricing registration discount if registration fees are paid with the ENS token versus other tokens such as Ether. This will drive demand for the ENS token, and bring more value to the token. I know this is currently frowned upon by those in charge but seems a much more sustainable way of making ENS viable for the long term. You obviously in addition to registrations, can charge transaction fees on Namechain in ENS tokens. I understand the ethos about ENS being used as strictly a DAO voting token, but since regulatory conditions have changed, that may not be as much of a concern. Don’t shoot me as the messenger, I am sure others in the ENS community are wondering. This is a much better approach than gigging your users/customers because transaction fees are currently low on mainnet. Your proposed approach rewards the 3L,4L holders, many of which could afford those expensive names and reaped the rewards of holding highly sought after 3L/4L names. Those mainstream users 5L and up are now going to be made to bear the brunt of this proposal. Sorry for my rant!!! I forgot to thank [danch.quixote] for the attempt, it was definitely a detailed research study.

I do not think the price for 5+ char domains should be increased. Sure a multi-year discount would be nice, but increasing this base price is going to hinder the adoption of ENS in my opinion.

I know for us crypto-native folks $5 sounds like peanuts, but for most of the world that is not.

If I’m onboarding someone in Africa or Asia, and I tell them they should register their name for 5 years, that’s already $25, in many of these countries that is a week or two of salary (yes I’m not kidding).

Now of course this is somewhat of an extreme, but we should not forget that most of the world for whom crypto is supposed to provide financial freedom and liberation for, this is already a very high price. Increasing it further you just push out a majority of the worlds population.

Now I’ve seen arguments going around that most people will just use subnames. Honestly most subnames are ugly and clunky, and if you’re going to force people in that direction by increasing pricing, then we are also sacrificing UX, and allowing void for competitors to fill.

Just my first reaction to this.

gm

First, great work @danch.quixote - it seems this has legs. I think the DAO would benefit greatly from more contributions of this type of exploratory research from a broad class of the ENS community. Diversity of contributors and thought is an end unto itself and it is a positive feedback loop for encouraging and growing DAO contributors and talent.

Seconded, both for benefit of the delegates and it’s important research backed proposals that directly impact the decentralized protocol, such as pricing, be as transparent as possible.

This reminds me of the airdrop mechanisms in certain respects, which principally aimed to reward end users. On one hand the airdrop rewarded multi-year registrations up to a point (8 years) - indicative of an end user - much like the proposed pricing model discount mechanism. Additionally, the airdrop rewarded users that set as a primary record (I think reverse record at the time).

From what I’ve seen most of the concern to this proposal is related to the 5+ character price increase. I sympathize with these arguments, and think the airdrop mechanisms could be helpful here in many respects.

As an example, a 5+ character set as primary might receive a discount to the original $5/year. This would tend to simultaneously creating friction for speculators achieving the goal of regulating registrations through the new pricing while benefiting end users and encouraging actual use intrinsically limited to 1 name/wallet. This carrot approach could even go one step further with discounts for setting avatars, headers, and records, for primary names further encouraging user behavior that has positive feedback loops and potential flywheel effects for growth and increasing friction for speculators to game.

It’s good to explore the topic, but I would be strongly against any changes to pricing.

Even though the protocol is in production, it is still far from being polished superstar app capturing hearts and mind, there is a looooong way to go.

Making name more expensive is like shooting your own leg, we need adoption, if anything they should be getting cheaper.

In anyway this is the last topic we should be discussing right now, we should focus on adoption and growth.

Having consistent pricing policy throughout the years is a crucial part of this, if we implement something like this, it would make matters worse, users will get confused with pricing policy etc.

The way to generate more revenue is by finishing the namechain, make it really solid product integrated anywhere and only then play with price.

Especially in my opinion all the other services out there provide alias effectively for free - your gmail alias is free, your not paying for it, not with money anyway. In contrast 5USD per year is very very very expensive.

Increasing prices is never going to be a popular move, and I’m seeing a lot of reflexive opposition that rejects the idea based on sentiment - without engaging in the substantial research and due diligence Danch has engaged in to arrive at this point. I believe his research to be sound, and it demonstrates an excellent estimate of the first-order effects of changing pricing.

Personally I’m highly supportive of the suggested changes, particularly since the increase in 5-character registration costs approach 0 for longer registrations (exactly the users we want to retain most) and are a substantial discount for non-speculative owners of 3- and 4- character names - these categories being significantly undersubscribed now that the speculative mania for them has diminished.

I’d also be generally supportive of:

  • Considering a reduction in price for longer names (say, 8+ characters) to preserve a lower-cost option for users who are particularly price sensitive.
  • Adjusting pricing brackets to account for character set. This is difficult to achieve onchain with complete fidelity, but there may be areas in which a simple test can distinguish a large number of names that should benefit from lower pricing.

Regarding timing, it’s unfortunately not practical to deploy these changes before ENSv2, as the DAO recently revoked its ownership of the Name Wrapper, which means there’s no way to upgrade the registrar controller used by it.

5 Likes

Thank you guys for your opinion.

I understand your concerns about how this might impact adoption and accessibility. However, it seems obvious to me that the pricing will need to change sooner or later, since there is a peg to fiat currency.

ENS is increasing its costs, and if you think that at some point they will be able to decrease – this will not happen, at least because now the infrastructure is being created that will need to be supported. Will providers, labs and contributors be able to support it for a fixed amount of money in dollars for the next, say, 20 years? No.


I don’t know how to speed up adoption and growth. However, I know how to raise the price without hurting it too much. Users are willing to pay more from an econometric point of view, and at the proposed price we will lose 5-10% of newcomers: these are quite moderative risks.

But we will receive a large amount of funds in order to direct them to development of


This is definitely an important topic. I live in Armenia, a poor country with a large number of crypto users. However, in my estimation, almost no one uses ENS. @0xc0de4c0ffee’s initiative would be useful for implementation here, since Armenians have their own alphabet with completely different characters.

For countries that do not have their own widely used set of unique characters, it may be worthwhile to launch funding for locally targeted programs that would promote Web3 and ENS. In the past, such initiatives (aimed mainly at Spanish-speaking and Arabic-speaking countries) were supported by small grants.

What should not be done in my opinion is to try to find a balanced single price for domains with the English alphabet that would suit Americans and, say, Jamaicans. It will always be unfair to poorer countries, no matter how low it is.


I am not suggesting to punish or reward any group of users. I predict a future decline in 3/4L registrations, so I suggest introducing a discount system, without which this category will not survive. As for me, it does not matter at all that someone once squeezed profit out of this. 5L+ users are willing to pay more than 5$/y, so I suggest increasing the price.


I’ve thought carefully about your comments and will try to work out an alternative before moving forward. I’ll explore the prerequisites for this division:

and I will try to select more conservative curves and calculate the consequences of their introduction. Those in which the price for the first year will be either lower, or which are closer to this:

(the asymptote in the current model is at the level of $5, that is, it will not be possible to average the price below $5/year).

3 Likes

This is a very important topic. Thank you for your work @danch.quixote!

I am not a data scientist so I hope you forgive any shortcomings in my analysis. I will try my best to explain it. But to summarize I would say that I agree with most of the proposition but I disagree on the most important hypothesis. Which is this one:

If an ENS user wants to register a name for his address he will 98% of the time register the name sooner or later. He may wait for gas to be at a relatively low short or medium term value, but he will end up registering it no matter what.

The first graph you shared is insightful. But the only conclusion I draw from it is that regular users wait for the best moment to register a name unlike speculators. I think that we can’t use the low proportion of regular users registering names when gas is high to infer things about wether or not these regular users will end up registering a name or not. So gas fee is not a good proxy to estimate the willingness to register specifically because of it’s volatility. Registration Gas fee is not a good estimator of price elasticity. Even psychologically the gas fee isn’t thought of as being part of the price. It is just a side problem that the user waits for to disappear.

Yes, the gas value impacts the number of registrations temporarily. We can not conclude that it impacts the total number of registrations.

HOWEVER

I do agree with what follows in the analysis:

When a user takes the decision to register a name at the instant t, the gas fee does play a role in the number of years he will register the name for as evidenced by the second graph.

This is why, although I was skeptical of a curved pricing model, I think I am now in favor of it to incentivize longer registrations.

Now let’s move to the price suggestions:

My price suggestions are based on psychological elements, that although not measurable without a survey, are very relevant imo.

This is why I would be in favor of a qualitative approach as suggested by @clowes.eth and I disagree with the following answer:

For 5L+: Like @sat I am against a price increase because I want to keep .eth names accessible for people in poor countries. However I may be in favor of it if we create a new category at 5 usd. (Maybe 7 char+)

For 3L: I think this category is the one that could bring the most revenue to the DAO if all the 3 letters get registered. And the only way to create a massive registration movement is to significantly lower the price of the first year because it is still seen by many in the community as prohibitively expensive. It is hard to give a price suggestion that would create this movement but I would say between 200 and 400.

For 4L: At the very least the same reduction in price applied to 3L should be applied to them for fairness. But I would suggest lowering the price even more in proportion for 4L because they are a lot less scarce.

You said this about 3L and 4L and I agree. And the only way to revive the secondary market is to significantly lower the price so all 3L and a lot of 4L get registered. I don’t see this happening without significant base price decrease.

I would be in favor of much lower prices for other alphabets and emojis.

As for the timing of implementation matters because as I said earlier I disagree with the premise that the ultimate number of registration could be estimated with gas (only a temporary issue).

You’re absolutely right to raise this. I’ve run into a similar issue trying to onboard users in Buenos Aires. Subnames have been a helpful workaround, but it’s not the same as owning a proper second-level domain.

Unless the goal is to frame 5+ character .eth names as luxury items in emerging markets—which, if so, I can understand—then I’d be curious whether any market research has been done in these regions where users tend to be more price-sensitive. We may be inadvertently excluding potential user bases in emergent markets, creating an opening for competitors to capture that segment.

On the other hand, ENS has the technical capacity to tokenize any domain name. With the upcoming Openbox integration and support for additional gTLDs (perhaps gTLDs that appeal to those emergent markets?), there may be an opportunity to diversify ENS’s revenue streams beyond .eth, allowing .eth to evolve into a more premium namespace while offering more accessible alternatives for global users.

3 Likes

@danch.quixote could you share the research publicly please?

It is difficult to reply without having full visibility on the research methodologies used.

Agree with many of the points raised by others.

1 Like

I just remembered that I saw some studies some time ago that showed that the effect of price increase on cigarette consumption was much more significant if the price was raised significantly once rather than raised a few times by small amounts each time.

This is why I think it’s better to decrease the price significantly once rather than risking doing it over multiple times and not getting the same effect on registrations.

Sure. I’ve copied all the research documentation to Google Drive from the Notion TeamSpace.

It’s unlikely to affect the discussion in any way - the documents are 95% calculations, and I’ve described all the relevant interpretation in the post. Please read the instructions before diving in.


Yes, they really are waiting for the moment when gas will cost less. This effect is already taken into account in the model, and the coefficient of the gas value itself (on the basis of which the risks are calculated) is adjusted for the presence of this effect.

However, it should not be overestimated. If ā€œ98%ā€ were really a thing, we would see spikes in registrations at the moments when gas dropped sharply after long-term high values ​​(let’s say it was $20 for 2 weeks, then dropped to $10), but this does not happen.

The only statistically significant effect occurs when gas falls relative to the previous day. In other words, if a user sees high gas, they are willing to wait 1 day to catch a better price, and if this does not happen, we see a refusal.


And again you hit the nail on the head! You have great potential as a data analyst.

Of course, I also took into account the volatility factor. Users register more names if they are offered a more stable price during the day. However, again, this effect does not work on larger timeframes - both speculators and regular users do not care that gas could vary greatly over the course of, say, a month.


I thought for a long time about how to survey users or at least analyze sentiments. I didn’t succeed. Do you have any specific ideas?

1 Like

Agreed, this is an issue that has been mentioned before: Limit short domain overcharge to alphanumeric characters to avoid linguistic discrimination - #11 by nick.eth

Especially if the focus is on attracting more real users, we should allow people with East Asian names to be able to get their ENS without having to pay a premium for it.

1 Like

This is really good data and interesting presentation, thank you @danch.quixote and everyone else putting in all the work.

I think the data is really well presented, but I’m not persuaded by a couple of the conclusions from the data. If the data doesn’t show higher demand for 5/6L names, I think logic still dictates that these are more valuable lengths. And although speculators may not blink at high gas fees, please note they are on the assumption that in the future gas fees may be negligible and registrations may be $5. The whole dynamic changes at $15. My understanding is, this breaks the assumption of a 5-10% user loss also.

If we adopt a system of lower renewal costs based on the length of the registration, it could incentivize users to take out a loan for a premium name, which worries me a bit.

Regarding users from poor countries, multi-year registrations may not be any help, I have seen a user drop her personal branded name because of the $5 fee. This $15 multi-year discount could turn into a regressive tax, where the successful pay it down to $6 and the less successful are paying $15 annually.

At $15 for a 5L domain, that is a steeper registration than .com, and we lose the precedent of .com’s success.

Personally, I think increased revenue helps everyone in the ecosystem, but I would rather see all prices go up 30% (and maybe increase annually on CPI) rather than any major changes. I mostly worry the adoption could stall and users could be confused. Otherwise, I would like to see how ENS could capitalize on name chain or other revenue sources to continue the growth.